India’s Sterling Assets
By
Dr. V. S. KRISHNA, M.A., Ph.D.
(Professor
of Economics, Andhra University)
One
of the major economic consequences of the present War is the change in the
position of India in the field of international finance. She has long been a
debtor country and the foreign debt of the Government of India was over Rs. 400
crores before the present War, and every year she had to pay about £30,000,000
to Britain in addition to what the British investors in private enterprises in
India were earning in the way of profits. During the present War, the
Government has been able to liquidate most of the foreign liabilities and the
Reserve Bank of India has accumulated sterling assets worth about Rs. 1,200
crores. Before discussing the question of the utilisation of these assets, it
is necessary to describe their origin with a view to remove some doubts
entertained by some British publicists regarding the legitimacy of the claims
of India in this respect.
The
obligations of Britain to India during the present War have arisen mainly from
two sources. These are:
I.
Commodity exports. Since the outbreak of the War, India has lost many of
her foreign markets for goods but her trade with Britain and the Empire
countries has shown a considerable export surplus. Britain has been obliged to
devote most of her resources to the production of war materials and,
consequently, her capacity to export goods abroad has diminished. She requires,
on the other hand, some essential commodities from India for which she could
not pay in kind.
The
figures relating to the foreign trade of India published by the Government show
the value of the exports on private account only. In addition to these, the
Government of India, through its Supply Department, has been placing orders for
essential materials required by the British Government in the Indian markets
and the Indian Government has been providing, in the first instance, the rupee
finance required for this purpose. The British Government pays for these
commodities in sterling in London, and as the Government of India requires
rupees for further purchases, the sterling thus acquired is transferred to the
Reserve Bank and rupees are obtained in return.
2.
Recoverable expenditure on the Army in India. According to the recommendations
of the Chatfield Committee of 1938, the external defence of India should be a
responsibility jointly shared by the Governments of India an Britain. In 1940,
an agreement was concluded between the two Governments regarding the
apportionment of this expenditure. Under the terms of this Agreement, the
Government of India to bear the following items of expenditure:
i
The normal effective cost of the Army in India under peace conditions:
ii
Additional cost due to rise in prices;
iii
The cost of war measures undertaken in the interests of India;
iv
A lump sum payment of one crore to meet the extra cost of maintaining India’s
external
defence troops overseas.
The
rest of the expenditure incurred on defence is recoverable from the British
Government. As in the case of purchases made in India, the British Government
pays the sums due under this head to the Indian Government in sterling and the
latter transfers the sterling to the Reserve Bank.
When
a private body or the Government tenders sterling, the Reserve Bank has to
purchase it at a rate not higher than Ish. 6 and 3/16 d. per rupee, provided it
is offered in amounts of not less than £ 10,000 at a time. If the amount of
sterling so purchased is not considerable, payment can be made from the Banking
Department. This causes a change in the assets held by that Department,
sterling being substituted for rupees. But the amount of sterling that can be
so acquired is limited. The Banking Department should have sufficient Indian
currency to meet the withdrawals of its depositors, and it is not desirable to
keep more sterling than what is required by those who have payments to make
abroad.
When
the sterling purchased is in excess of what can be taken by the Banking
Department, the Issue Department of the Bank comes to its aid. The Reserve Bank
Act has laid down that at least forty per cent of the assets of the Issue
Department should be in the form of gold or sterling securities and that the
amount of gold should not be less than forty crores in value. The Bank is
therefore permitted to issue notes without limit with sterling. securities as
cover, provided it has the minimum gold prescribed.
The
rupee finance required for the operations undertaken by the Government of India
on behalf of the British Government is provided mainly by the Issue Department
of the Reserve Bank. The British Government pays the Indian Government in
sterling and the latter exchanges sterling
for rupee notes. These transactions have greatly increased both the note issue
and the sterling securities held by the Reserve Bank. In the year 1938-39, the
note issue amounted, on an average, to about 210 crores in value and the
sterling securities to about 68 crores. In recent weeks they are
about 1,000 crores and 900 crores respectively. The sterling held by the
Banking Department increased from an average of about 4 crores to about 300
crores. In recent months the expansion of currency has been taking place at a
slower pace than during the last two years because the Allied Governments are
obtaining part of their rupee finance by the sale of gold through the Reserve
Bank.
It
is now admitted by most persons that this method of financing the War effort
coupled with the difficulty of expanding production, has been responsible for
the great rise in prices in recent years. The finance thus provided
is not obtained from the voluntary savings of the people, but the
saving is imposed on people many of whom cannot afford to reduce their
consumption.
The
claim of India for the sterling assets so accumulated has been questioned in
some quarter on the ground that they are the result of India’s inadequate
contribution to the common war effort. Where the gain from an action cannot be
estimated in terms of money and the interests of the co-operating parties
cannot be separated, there is no other equitable basis for the distribution of
the burden except that of ability to pay. This is the accepted principle in the
matter of internal taxation and this principle has been accepted in connection
with the organisation to be set up for giving relief to the inhabitants of the
areas devastated by the War.
The
ability of a country to pay for a war depends mainly on two factors, viz., the
extent to which its production can be increased and the difference between its
peace-time income and the amount necessary for satisfying the minimum customary
needs of the people. To these another circumstance might be added, viz., the
efficacy of taxation and loans for transferring surplus resources from the
civilian to the war use.
The
productive power of Britain increased considerably during the War and so part
of her War expenditure is met by increased production. Due to the backwardness
of India with regard to industrial development, she has to depend on foreign
countries for the supply of some essentials. Till 1,942 her industrial
production showed some increase, but since that year some of the major
industries have been producing less because of the difficulty of obtaining
certain essential products. When the War has reached her borders and when,
therefore, she has to make her maximum effort, India’s productive capacity has
diminished.
It
is a well-known fact that the national income of India is not sufficient to
provide even the bare physical needs of her total population. Recent
investigations in Britain have shown that when there is normal employment even
the lowest paid working class family does not suffer from want except in cases
were the size of a family is more than the average. This shows that the
normal income of the people is mole than what is necessary to
provide for the physical needs of the people.
It
has been calculated that the per capita income in Britain is more
than 15 times the income in India. This does not take into account the
differences in the purchasing power of a unit of income in the
two countries, and it should not therefore be concluded that the
enjoyment that an average Englishman is able to command is 15 times the
enjoyment which an Indian gets. An Australian statistician, Collin
Clark, has compared the purchasing powers of money in different countries,
and on the basis of his calculations, it may be stated that, roughly, an
Indian enjoys about one-fifth of the purchasing power commanded by an
Englishman.
Britain
is said to be devoting about 60 per cent of her national income
to war purposes. It is not possible to make an accurate
calculation in the case of India but a rough idea of the magnitude of her
effort may be given.
The
estimated war expenditure of the Central Government for the year 1,944-45 is
over Rs. 300 crores, and past experience shows that the actual expenditure
always exceeds the estimated amount during the War years. As the cost of the
recent operations in Assam is to be borne by India, the actual
expenditure might be nearly 400 crores. It has been calculated
that the purchases made on behalf of the United Nations, for which we
do not get the equivalent in goods during the War, are of the
value of about 300 crores per year. To these two figures we have to add the
donations to the various War Funds and the expenditure of the Provincial and
Central Governments on A. R. P. and other measures which are not shown
under War expenditure. The total contribution is therefore not less than
700 crores.
The
National income of British India was estimated to have been about Rs.
1,760 crores in 1931-32. Prices have risen by about 250%
during the War but unless wages, salaries, rents, interest and profits
rise proportionately, the total money income of the country does not
increase to the same extent. As it can safely be assumed that these have not
risen proportionately and as the physical volume of production
has been falling lately, it can reasonably be assumed that the present
money income of British India is about Rs. 3,500 crores. India is
therefore devoting about 20% of her national income to war
purposes, assuming that most of the contribution is made by
British India. The sacrifice of the Indians who have to forego one-fifth of
their peace-time enjoyment is greater than the sacrifice of the Englishmen
who have given up three-fifths of their five-fold income.
The
burden on some sections of the people has been made heavier by the methods
adopted for transferring real income from the civilian to war purposes. Loans
and tax have not yielded the required amount and so the instrument of inflation
has been resorted to. This has hit some important sections of the community
very hard and the consequences are too well-known to require special mention.
It is said that in Britain health conditions have improved during the War and
the mortality rate has fallen. The common people might not have such a variety
of food stuffs as in peace-time, but they have a sufficient quantity of
wholesome food. The statistics relating to public health and famines in India reveal
quite a different picture.
As
the accumulation of these sterling assets involved great suffering which has
taken the form of malnutrition, deterioration of sanitary conditions and even
actual starvation in some parts, it is but natural to suggest that they might
be utilised to relieve the suffering immediately. Several Indian public men and
economists are stressing the need for inducing Britain to release these assets
immediately, so that goods may be purchased with them and imported into India.
If consumers’ goods are imported the price level might fall immediately, and if
producers’ goods are got, production in India might increase. It may take time
to effect a decrease in prices but it would be more advantageous from a
long-term point of view. A similar result might be obtained if Britain and
other Allied countries are asked to pay in kind for the commodities which they
buy from now onwards. This will decrease the growth of sterling assets and
further expansion of currency would not be necessary.
There
are certain factors limiting the use of these measures. The industries of the
United Nations are fully engaged in production for war purposes and those
countries may not be able to spare goods for civilian consumption in such large
quantities as we require. Further, the goods that these countries could supply
are not those that are most urgently required by the common people of India, viz.,
the staple foodstuffs. Importation of goods consumed by the higher classes
might reduce the general price level but this would not help the common man.
The
full utilisation of these assets is therefore a post-War problem. When normal
trade connections are re-established after the War, India would be able to
obtain some of the essential commodities in exchange for her exports and the
use of sterling assets for providing the deficiency in the matter of foodstuffs
might not be necessary.
During
the post-War period there will be many competing claims on these sterling
assets.
In
the first place, there is the monetary requirement. The Reserve Bank has to
keep a certain amount of foreign exchange to meet possible adverse foreign
balances but this does not require a large proportion of the present assets.
Before the War, when the foreign liabilities were high, the Reserve Bank
was keeping only about 40 crores in gold and 70 crores in sterling. These amounts
might be sufficient after the War.
Secondly,
the assets might be utilised for liquidating the remaining
foreign obligations of India, like the payment of pensions to retired
Government servants, etc., and the liquidation of foreign capital
invested in private undertakings in India. These two items are
expected to claim about half the present balances, but it is
to be considered whether it is desirable to liquidate these
in view of the fact that for other purposes India might have to
run into debt again, even if the whole of the present balance is
uitilised for these purposes.
Thirdly,
there is a large deferred demand for foreign comsumers’ goods and at
least in the first years of peace India may import more on this account
than what she could export. There is a widespread view, especially
among the industrialists, that the sterling assets should not be utilised for
this purpose. When there is likely to be a large demand
for producers’ goods, it is not considered desirable to
add to this the demand for consumers’ goods also for which substitutes might
be found in India.
Control
and rationing are necessary in the matter of imports for some time after
the War, but it may not be desirable to prohibit the
importation of all consumers’ goods. If any scheme for rapid industrialisation
is put into operation, which would make it necessary to
give preference to the development of basic industries, we might have to draw
upon foreign countries for some consumers’ goods till our industries are in a
position to produce those goods in required quantities. The increased
investment in basic industries leads to an increase in the income of the
factors of production, which would increase the demand for consumers
goods. As, in the first stages of industrialisation, these goods
would not be coming into the market in required quantities, there would be an
inflationary rise in prices. As the Indian economy is already subjected
to a great strain by war-time inflation, schemes for economic reconstruction
would not have the willing co-operation of the people if they
involve further inflation. This is a point which the Bombay Plan
has not taken into account. If the importation of consumers’ goods is
necessary, then it does not make much difference whether we use the
existing sterling assets or raise foreign loans for this purpose.
Fourthly,
after the War India might have to make her own arrangements for the
defence of the country. This will require large equipment, a major part of
which has to be imported from abroad. This will impose a great strain on the
foreign trade position of the country. It may, however, be safely assumed that
after the War there would be a long peace. Organisation and equipment of
fighting forces might therefore be done gradually as the country becomes
industrialised.
Lastly,
it is the schemes for raising living standards in India that will make a
heavy demand on the foreign balances of India. The problem of abolishing want
has become prominent since Roosevelt made his pronouncement on the Four
Freedoms. In countries in which production has reached such a level as to
provide the required necessaries for all people, the question one of fairer
distribution of income and of guaranteeing a minimum income during non-earning
periods. In countries like India where the total national income is not
sufficient to provide even the bare necessaries, the question is one of
increased production and better distribution. Industrialisation is considered
to be the primary objective of future economic policy, and if any comprehensive
scheme for this purpose is adopted, India would have to import equipment in
large quantities from foreign countries. An idea of the magnitude of the
requirements may be obtained from the Bombay Plan which requires external
finance to the extent of Rs. 2,600 crores of which a little less than half is
covered by the present sterling assets.
The
Bombay Plan takes into account the external finance required for importing
capital goods only and it does not include the other claims. As was argued
above, the other claims have to be met to some extent. It is desirable to have
a single authority which will mobilise all the sources of external finance and
distribute it among the different objects according to a scheme of priorities.
The
main sources of external finance are sterling balances, loans that might be
raised, export of commodities and hoarded gold, and external finance will be
demanded by producers for capital goods, consumers for consumers’ goods,
Government for equipping the fighting forces and for development of public
utilities, and, lastly, the Reserve Bank for monetary reserve. Generally
speaking, it is not necessary to earmark the finance obtained from a particular
source for a particular purpose. The total finance may be apportioned according
to the importance of the demand, irrespective of the source from which money is
obtained. In this matter it is however necessary to take two points into
consideration:
I.
Borrowing from foreign countries will mostly be done in future through the
International Capital Bank. According to the recent agreement, loans will be
granted through this source for productive purposes only. It is therefore
necessary to earmark the loans to be raised for industrial purposes.
2.
The sterling assets are now part of the cover against the notes in circulation.
If a deflationary crisis is to be avoided, the volume of notes should not be
reduced unless the velocity of circulation of money increases. In giving effect
to any scheme for the utilisation of the sterling assets, its effect on
monetary circulation should be kept in view. The evils that are caused by
inflation cannot be corrected by adopting the opposite policy of deflation.
If
the sterling assets are liquidated some other assets prescribed by law have to
be substituted. According to the Reserve Bank Act these are: gold, sterling
securities, rupee securities, rupee coins, bills of exchange and promissory
notes. Under the existing money market conditions the only alternative cover
for notes are rupee securities of the Government until the use of the right
type of bills becomes general. The question to be considered therefore is
whether the mechanism by which the purchases of foreign capital or consumption
goods by private individuals or corporations are financed, would automatically
substitute rupee securities when the sterling securities are withdrawn and
cashed.
When
India imports more than what she exports and when the excess is greater than
the foreign balance held by the Banking Department, notes will be tendered to
the Issue Department, and when sterling is provided, notes of an equivalent
value would be cancelled. This will reduce the money in circulation unless the
Government issues its pronotes and borrows from the Reserve Bank, and spends
the amount thus obtained. The Bank will have an eligible cover and the currency
will get back into circulation. If the new industries to be started are
State-owned, this method would solve the difficulty, but it is not yet clear
what role the State will play in the post-War industrial development.
If
private enterprise continues to play an important role and if finance for new
enterprises is to be raised from private investors, the State should spend
considerable amounts on public works or defence. Only then the monetary
mechanism will work smoothly. The view held by some economists that during the
period of industrialisation the State should not spend much on public utilities
is tenable only in so far as those works are concerned which require large
external finance. Unless it undertakes works which require mainly Indian
resources and which should be financed through loans, deflation might follow
and defeat any scheme of industrial advancement.
Public
attention has recently been devoted not so such to the problem of proper
utilisation of the sterling assets as to the possibility of converting the
assets into goods of the right type and at the time we require It is also
feared that Britain might try to reduce her liability by depreciating her
currency in which our assets are expressed.
The
question whether we shall get an equivalent for the sacrifice we have made,
cannot be answered easily. It is natural for every State to try to reduce the
burden of foreign obligations but the question is whether Britain will find it
advantageous to reduce her obligations to India through currency depreciation.
The obligations to several Empire countries are expressed in sterling but her
obligations to outside countries are in terms of other units. If Britain
depresses the pound, the burden of the latter would increase.
Another
factor in policy of Britain is being stressed at present. For an old industrial
country, the problem of finding suitable openings for the use of savings made
when there is full employment is a difficult one. For such countries the
building of an export surplus is very important and this may be done either by
raising loans abroad or discharging past obligations. The existence of foreign
obligations acts as a stimulus to business activity and Britain will be able to
maintain full employment successfully so long as these foreign obligations
exist. It is not therefore the danger of reducing the obligations that we have
to fear but that of keeping them for an unduly long period.
There
is another point which is of importance in this connection. India and Britain
can come to a mutually advantageous agreement with regard to the settlement of
this question if Britain is in a position to supply goods required by India at
competitive prices. If any scheme for rapid industrialisation is put into
operation, this country would have to get commodities by exploiting all the
available sources of external finance within a period of 10 to 15 years. The demand
for goods in the early years will be specially heavy, and in these years,
Britain may have to devote all her resources to the reconstruction of the
devastated areas. Further, an agreement like this will restrict the choice of
the Indian producers and consumers and it may retard the growth of multilateral
trade, the establishment of which is desired by most countries. It may
therefore be necessary to convert a part of the sterling into other currencies
and every scheme for the liquidation of the present balances should make
provision for this.
The
British, American and Canadian schemes for Post-War International Monetary
Organisation referred to the problem of the abnormal war balances. The British
scheme merely, mentioned that it was desirable to devise a plan for making
these balances liquid without imposing great strain on the debtor countries,
but the other two schemes suggested a specific plan for settling the debts. The
schemes imposed obligations on both the creditor and the debtor countries–on the
former, the obligation of purchasing goods from the debtor countries with part
of the balances, and, on the latter, the obligation of building up an export
surplus with non-creditor countries and placing their currencies at the
disposal of the creditors. A restriction was placed on the amount of the debts
that could be settled in this way through the monetary organisation but the
principle suggested in the schemes was a reasonable one.
The
Monetary Conference held at Bretton Woods refused to consider the question of
the abnormal War balances in connection with the scheme for establishing an
International Monetary Fund. It was argued that the Fund would deal with
problems arising out of current trade transactions only and the widening of the
scope of the Fund might make the new organization unsuccessful. The question is
therefore to be settled through negotiations between the creditors and debtors.
It
is true that the new experiment in world monetary co-operation should not be
burdened with unnecessary complications but it is to be considered whether the
exclusion of this problem would ensure the success of the new organisation.
The
working of the League of Nations has shown that if member countries are allowed
to settle important questions independently of, and not through, the
international organisation, few questions would be settled through it. The
abnormal war balances, provision of long-term capital to industrially backward
countries, and other important problems which affect international trade are
outside the purview of the monetary organisation. In the case of many countries
the quantity of imports or exports on these accounts may exceed the quantity on
current account and therefore the monetary organisation would not be concerned
with the major part of the international trade transactions arising immediately
after the War. This would weaken the organisation.
Further,
it is one of the aims of the International Monetary Fund to discourage
bilateral trade agreements and encourage the growth of multilateral trade
transactions. If the abnormal war balances are to be settled by agreements
between creditor and debtor countries, bilateral trade agreements cannot be
avoided. The decision of the Conference is therefore not accord with one of the
major objectives of the Fund.
As
things stand at present, the question of the liquidation of the sterling assets
of India is to be decided by negotiation between India and Britain. Britain
would naturally press for the acceptance of goods spread over a large number of
years, while the interest of India requires the conversion of at least a part
of the balance into other currencies. As Britain is indebted in a
similar way to several other countries, it is not possible for her to concede
this to all her creditors but it should be emphasised that the case of India is
a special one. Accumulation of sterling assets by countries like Australia and
Canada did not involve so much suffering as in the case of India. The
accumulated balances do not represent the voluntary savings of the Indian
people and they are due to the encroachment on the consumption of the people
which is already low. The only way in which this could be made good is by
helping India to have an economic organisation that would ensure adequate
living standards.
It
has been suggested that India could borrow through the International Capital
Bank an amount equivalent to the sterling assets and this loan might be
guaranteed by both India and Britain. There are certain objections to this
proposal. Both India and Britain would have to borrow heavily after the War for
reconstruction purposes. There is already a plan under consideration for the
grant of a big dollar loan by the U. S. A. to Britain. India needs external
help in addition to the sterling assets if the efficiency of her economic
system is to be raised. It is to be considered whether the Capital Bank would
be prepared to arrange such large loans to the two countries. Further, the
sterling assets of India are in the form of short-term paper which carries a
low rate of interest. The long-term loans to be raised would carry a higher
rate. It is not advantageous to India to take a loan at higher rate of interest
on the security of assets which carry a lower rate. The transaction would be
advantageous only if Britain would undertake the repayment of the loan with
interest to the Capital Bank.
The
problem could be solved only with the co-operation of the U. S. A. Her
productive power has enormously increased during the War, and if she follows a
policy of full employment, she has to maintain an export surplus till the
consumption of her people rises to a much higher level than at present. After
the War she will be the only country, besides Britain, which can supply the
goods which India wants. If she grants a big loan for the industrial
development of India, goods which are more urgently required might be purchased
from her and those that could be spread over time might be taken from Britain
in exchange for the sterling assets.
Thus
a satisfactory solution of the question depends on the co-operation of not only
India and Britain but also the assistance of other countries like the
U. S. A. The United Nations have decided, rightly or wrongly, that different
international economic problems should be dealt with by different bodies after
the War. They have agreed to have one body for Rehabilitation, another for
monetary problems arising out of current trade transactions and a third
for long-term lending. The settlement of war-time balances is one of the
essential conditions for reconstructing world economy after the War, and so
another international a agreement is necessary on
this question.