SOCIO-ECONOMIC STRUCTURE vs. POLITICAL DEMOCRACY
The
Case of the United
States
K.
RANGA RAO
Lecturer
in
Sociology, Andhra University, Waltair
The United States of
America is considered the first successful
modern democratic country in the world. Tocqueville praised the country for its
democracy, local self-government and voluntary associations. The constitution
with its separation of powers and declaration of freedom of speech and
association for each citizen strongly advocates the establishment of a democratic
and pluralistic society. However, of late, Some
thinkers, mainly sociologists, voiced concern about the growth of ‘power elite’
and ‘monolithic power structure’ in the country. Notable among them G. Wright
Mills declared that the U.
S. A. as a whole is ruled only by a small
‘power elite’. He wrote: “America
is now in considerable part more a formal political democracy than a democratic
social structure, and even the formal Political mechanisms are weak. The long-time trend of business and government to become
more intricately and deeply involved with each other has, in this epoch,
reached a point of explicitness not before
evident.” 1
Floyd
Hunter pointed out that the nucleus of top Power structure of the U. S. A.
constitutes not more than three hundred people at most and that there are only
about a hundred ‘number-one’ men who can be considered the top echelon of
power. 2 Lipset
writes that the “percentage of the potential electorate voting in national
American elections is now considerably below what it was in 1896, when 80 per
cent of those eligible went to the polls. From a low in 1920 of 49 per cent, in
more recent elections the figure has oscillated around 60 per cent. As
the political scientist V. O. Key, Jr. points out, this is considerably lower
than the participation in other major democracies like Great Britain, Holland
and Norway.
3
Besides
such studies at the national level, studies of community leadership and
decision-making throw more light on the functioning of democracy at the community
level. A number of sociologists, political scientists and also economists are
taking more and more interest in such studies with the basic belief that the
development and maintenance of democratic institutions at the national level
rests upon viable democratic patterns at the local community level. Social
workers too began to take interest in such studies in view of the fact that
much of community organisation, its success or failure, is linked up with the
nature of the community power structure.
It
was Floyd Hunter’s study of a Southern Regional City that made a tremendous
impact in this field even though long before him the Lynds
4 have reported that leadership and
influence in Middletown
were virtually vested in only one large business family. Hunter found in the
Regional City a very limited number of businessmen who weilded
a great deal of influence over a number of community issues and problems.5
A major breakthrough then came with Dahl’s study of New Haven.6
Dahl mainly tried to analyse whether or not the same
set of people influenced decisions in various fields of the community. In his
study Dahl employed the method of ‘event’ or ‘issue’ analysis as against the ‘reputational’ approach of Hunter. His analysis of important
decisions revealed the fact that political leaders also played important roles
in certain spheres of community life and that the business leaders had no
monopoly as such. Since Dahl thus found little overlap between the leaders he
concluded that New Haven represented a
pluralistic society unlike the monolithic power structure of Hunter’s Regional City. However, it is pertinent to note
that Dahl came to the conclusion as he did in spite of the fact that he found
only a few leaders at the top and there was very limited participation in
elections or in voluntary organisations on the part
of the public at large.
In
their subsequent studies the researchers adopted both reputational
and decisional approaches. These later studies also made refinements in their
analyses of leadership patterns. Freeman and his colleagues analysed
as many as 39 decisions and concluded that: “If Syracuse ever was a monolithic community, it
is very far from that today. But it is equally far from what high school civics
texts portray as a local democracy with an active and effective citizenry.”
7 Bonjean
8 found visible, concealed and symbolic leaders in a North Carolina city.
Similarly, Freeman and his colleagues classified leaders into
institutional leaders, effectors, and activists. Such analyses undoubtedly explain
more in detail about the characteristics and background of the community
leaders but do not basically differ in their views as to the very nature of the
community leadership.
Robert
Presthus, a political scientist, systematically
compared two communities so as to find out the extent of pluralistic
characteristics in each. He employed both the methods of ‘reputation’ and’
decisions’, and found them together useful in the analysis of community power
structure. To him the indexes of pluralism were: group membership, individual
participation, and organisational participation. His
conclusions are highly instructive. He wrote: “Our findings in Edgewood generally support earlier research of
sociologists who found a tendency toward eliticism in
community power structures which were usually dominated by economic elites. In
Riverview, the decision structure remains highly concentrated, but political
leaders play the major role. Regarding the restriction of active participation
to the few, the more recent findings of political scientists are quite
similar.” 9 Commenting upon the
assumptions made and conclusions arrived at by Dahl and other political
scientists, Presthus wrote: “…..historical emphasis
upon individualism and a rough equality of bargaining power among groups has
been subjugated to the assumption that pluralism exists if specialisation
and competition characterize groups of leaders who constitute some one-half of
1 per cent of the community. Certainly this definition meets prevailing
conditions of group organization and political access but it seems to omit some
of the conditions and normative by-products traditionally associated with
pluralism.” 10 Antonio and Form
wrote very succinctly: “Pluralism emerges in the American community (only) when
the business-professional groups are successfully challenged by the working
class and ethnic groups. Until that occurs, much of what may pass as pluralism
may be nothing but a struggle for status among business-professional
factions...” 11
The
above analysis thus supports the sociological thesis that: “A social structure
is, itself, a structure of power...though liberal capitalism has theoretically
rested upon individuals, it has factually rested upon classes of
like-circumstanced individuals–the classes being erected fundamentally on
economic interest and power; and it has been the fact that this social
structure of classes has been primarily economic–despite the avowed democratic
equality in the social structure and democratic professions of the political institutions.”
12
1 C.
Wright Mills: A. Kornhauser (Ed): Problems of
Power in American Democracy, Wayne
State University
Press. 1959. p. 162.
2 Bell
et al., Public Leadership, Chandler Publishing Company. 1961. p.
15
3 Lipset, S. M.: Political
Man, Anchor Books. 1960. p. 185
4 Lynd and Lynd: Middle
Town in Transition, New York, Harcourt
Brace. 1937.
5 Hunter,
F.: Community Power Structure, Chapel Hill, University of North
Carolina Press.
6 Dahl,
R. A.: Who Governs, New Hayen, Yale University
Press. 1961.
7 Freeman,
L. C. et al: Metropolitan Decision Making. Syracuse University
Press. 1962. p. 27
8 Bonjean, C. M: Community
Leadership: A case study and conceptual refinement. American
Journal of Sociology. May 1963.
9 Presthus, R: Men at
the Top. Oxford University Press. 1964. p. 430.
10
Presthus, R: Men at the Top. Oxford University
Press. 1964. p. 430
11 Antonio
and Form: Influentials in two Border
Cities. University
of Notre Dame Press.
1965. p. 231.
12 Lynd, R. C. in Kornhauser (ed), cited. P. 23-24
Back